Buy new:
-17% $18.24
FREE delivery Monday, May 20 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Ships from: Amazon
Sold by: Lofted Leaves
$18.24 with 17 percent savings
List Price: $22.00

The List Price is the suggested retail price of a new product as provided by a manufacturer, supplier, or seller. Except for books, Amazon will display a List Price if the product was purchased by customers on Amazon or offered by other retailers at or above the List Price in at least the past 90 days. List prices may not necessarily reflect the product's prevailing market price.
Learn more
Get Fast, Free Shipping with Amazon Prime FREE Returns
FREE delivery Monday, May 20 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
$$18.24 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$18.24
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Ships from
Amazon
Ships from
Amazon
Sold by
Sold by
Returns
30-day easy returns
30-day easy returns
This item can be returned in its original condition for a full refund or replacement within 30 days of receipt.
Returns
30-day easy returns
This item can be returned in its original condition for a full refund or replacement within 30 days of receipt.
Payment
Secure transaction
Your transaction is secure
We work hard to protect your security and privacy. Our payment security system encrypts your information during transmission. We don’t share your credit card details with third-party sellers, and we don’t sell your information to others. Learn more
Payment
Secure transaction
We work hard to protect your security and privacy. Our payment security system encrypts your information during transmission. We don’t share your credit card details with third-party sellers, and we don’t sell your information to others. Learn more
$5.99
Get Fast, Free Shipping with Amazon Prime FREE Returns
Shipped fast and reliably through the Amazon Prime program! Book may contain some writing, highlighting, and or cover damage. Shipped fast and reliably through the Amazon Prime program! Book may contain some writing, highlighting, and or cover damage. See less
FREE delivery Tuesday, May 21 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
$$18.24 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$18.24
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Access codes and supplements are not guaranteed with used items.
Kindle app logo image

Download the free Kindle app and start reading Kindle books instantly on your smartphone, tablet, or computer - no Kindle device required.

Read instantly on your browser with Kindle for Web.

Using your mobile phone camera - scan the code below and download the Kindle app.

QR code to download the Kindle App

Something went wrong. Please try your request again later.

Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness Hardcover – Unabridged, April 8, 2008

4.5 4.5 out of 5 stars 1,818 ratings

{"desktop_buybox_group_1":[{"displayPrice":"$18.24","priceAmount":18.24,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"18","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"24","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"xYF%2Fy9JtOPoeL58u%2FVpKi92zJqoUsO42v4xR5X4NKFLYV7ziiL23eRQcFe926%2BHSqONNmca2JQkACP380dFRMtikUuHQsoPScbvvtQJtrer%2F1pMY8ASxybMtjaiUB269V1jUrKiJMSeFQjhH%2Fsp%2FmkGlzWrI0GwbEhGCMsbpnnByfAXkAr2qtFFtKI1%2BoC9I","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"NEW","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":0}, {"displayPrice":"$5.99","priceAmount":5.99,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"5","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"99","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"xYF%2Fy9JtOPoeL58u%2FVpKi92zJqoUsO42ofHzLZs9y923TUAxlCb9%2BPLI85wIuAcMfgwd3JTdh1b6lxuNqif3fFncKNxsz%2FWQ%2BEaR4kH4uUMG%2BIIZlMllcVZ6vMc5D%2B1M2yT8gKpW2kq5s%2F6eCI811atXZ0rO06m85lLfjE%2F%2FLJVLZgUl%2FtgjBEb7ob5GmwDg","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"USED","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":1}]}

Purchase options and add-ons

A New York Times bestseller with more than 1.5 million copies sold

Named a Best Book of the Year by the Economist and the Financial Times
 
“An essential read . . . loaded with good ideas that financial-service executives, policy makers, Wall Street mavens, and all savers can use.”—John F. Wasik, Boston Globe
 
“Save the planet, save yourself. Do-gooders, policymakers, this one's for you.”—Newsweek
 
Every day, we make decisions on topics ranging from personal investments to schools for our children to the meals we eat to the causes we champion. Unfortunately, we often choose poorly. Nobel laureate Richard Thaler and legal scholar and bestselling author Cass Sunstein explain in this important exploration of choice architecture that, being human, we all are susceptible to various biases that can lead us to blunder. Our mistakes make us poorer and less healthy; we often make bad decisions involving education, personal finance, health care, mortgages and credit cards, the family, and even the planet itself.

In
Nudge, Thaler and Sunstein invite us to enter an alternative world, one that takes our humanness as a given. They show that by knowing how people think, we can design choice environments that make it easier for people to choose what is best for themselves, their families, and their society. Using colorful examples from the most important aspects of life, Thaler and Sunstein demonstrate how thoughtful “choice architecture” can be established to nudge us in beneficial directions without restricting freedom of choice. Nudge offers a unique new take—from neither the left nor the right—on many hot-button issues, for individuals and governments alike. This is one of the most engaging and provocative books to come along in many years.
Read more Read less

The Amazon Book Review
The Amazon Book Review
Book recommendations, author interviews, editors' picks, and more. Read it now

Frequently bought together

$18.24
Get it as soon as Monday, May 20
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
Sold by Lofted Leaves and ships from Amazon Fulfillment.
+
$8.95
Get it as soon as Sunday, May 19
In Stock
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
+
$8.41
Get it as soon as Monday, May 20
In Stock
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
Total price:
To see our price, add these items to your cart.
Details
Added to Cart
Some of these items ship sooner than the others.
Choose items to buy together.

Editorial Reviews

Review

"[A] new book applying the lessons of social psychology and behavioral economics to everything from health care to climate maintenance. The authors of Nudge . . . agree with economists who'd like to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by imposing carbon taxes or a cap-and-trade system, but they think people need extra guidance."―John Tierney, New York Times

"Two University of Chicago professors sketch a new approach to public policy that takes into account the odd realities of human behavior, like the deep and unthinking tendency to conform. Even in areas―like energy consumption―where conformity is irrelevant. Thaler has documented the ways people act illogically."―Barbara Kiviat,
Time

"A manifesto for using the recent behavioral research to help people, as well as government agencies, companies and charities, make better decisions."―David Leonhardt,
The New York Times Magazine

"Engaging, enlightening."―George Scialabba,
Boston Sunday Globe

"Sunstein and Thaler are very persuasive. . . . Great fun to read."―Dahlia Lithwick,
Slate

"An engaging and insightful tour through the evidence that most human beings don't make decisions in the way often characterized in elementary economics textbooks, along with a rich array of suggestions for enabling many of us to make better choices, both for ourselves and for society. . . . The conceptual argument is powerful, and most of the authors' suggestions are common sense at its best. . . . For that we should all applaud loudly."―Benjamin M. Friedman,
New York Times Book Review

"By a 'nudge,' Thaler and Sunstein mean a policy intervention into choice architecture that is easy and inexpensive to avoid and that alters people's behavior in a predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing an individual's economic incentives. . . . Thaler and Sunstein stress that if 'incentives and nudges replace requirements and bans, government will be both smaller and more modest.'"—George F. Will,
Newsweek

". . . an excellent rendition of how human beings view choices and make decisions."—Gurumurthy Kalyanaram & Sunanda Muralidharan,
International Journal of Pharmaceutical and Healthcare Management Vol 5.4

"As important a book as I've read in perhaps 20 years. It is a book that people interested in any aspect of public policy should read. It is a book that people interested in politics should read. It is a book that people interested in ideas about human freedom should read. It is a book that people interested in promoting human welfare should read."―Barry Schwartz,
The American Prospect

"
Nudge helps us understand our weaknesses, and suggests savvy ways to counter them."―Emily Bobrow, New York Observer

"This
Poor Richard's Almanack for the 21st century . . . shares both the sagacity and the witty and accessible style of its 18th century predecessor."―Benjamin Gregg, Law and Politics Book Review

"As bookstore shelves fill up with works by parlor-room thinkers who would entertain us with their economic nonsense, an entertaining book that also deeply informs could get lost in the shuffle. That book is
Nudge. . . . Thaler and Sunstein's . . . attempt to deal with difficult issues is always stimulating."—Gene Epstein, Barron's (One of this season's recommended page-turners on economic, financial and political-economic issues)

"Entertaining, engaging, and well written. . . . Highly recommended."―
Choice

A 2007 Top Seller in Business and Economics as compiled by YBP Library Services


Selected as a finalist for the 2008 TIAA-CREF Paul A. Samuelson Award, given by the TIAA-CREF Institute

Named one of the best business books of 2008 by
The Financial Times


Silver medal winner of the 2008 Book of the Year Award in the category of Business & Economics, presented by
ForeWord magazine

Winner of the 2010 Kulp-Wright Book Award, given by the American Risk and Insurance Association

"In this utterly brilliant book, Thaler and Sunstein teach us how to steer people toward better health, sounder investments, and cleaner environments without depriving them of their inalienable right to make a mess of things if they want to. The inventor of behavioral economics and one of the nation's best legal minds have produced the manifesto for a revolution in practice and policy. Nudge won't nudge you―it will knock you off your feet."―Daniel Gilbert, professor of psychology, Harvard University, Author of Stumbling on Happiness




"This is an engaging, informative, and thoroughly delightful book. Thaler and Sunstein provide important lessons for structuring social policies so that people still have complete choice over their own actions, but are gently nudged to do what is in their own best interests. Well done."—Don Norman, Northwestern University, Author of The Design of Everyday Things and The Design of Future Things




"This book is terrific. It will change the way you think, not only about the world around you and some of its bigger problems, but also about yourself."—Michael Lewis, author of The Blind Side: Evolution of a Game and Liar's Poker




"Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein's Nudge is a wonderful book: more fun than any important book has a right to be—and yet it is truly both."—Roger Lowenstein, author of When Genius Failed



"How often do you read a book that is both important and amusing, both practical and deep? This gem of a book presents the best idea that has come out of behavioral economics. It is a must-read for anyone who wants to see both our minds and our society working better. It will improve your decisions and it will make the world a better place."—Daniel Kahneman, Princeton University, Nobel Laureate in Economics




About the Author

Richard H. Thaler, winner of the 2017 Nobel Prize in Economics, is the Ralph and Dorothy Keller Distinguished Service Professor of Behavioral Science and Economics at the University of Chicago’s Graduate School of Business.  His latest book is Misbehaving:  The Making of Behavioral Economics.  Cass R. Sunstein is the Robert Walmsley University Professor at Harvard Law School and most recently the author of Impeachment:  A Citizen’s Guide.
 
 

Product details

  • ASIN ‏ : ‎ 0300122233
  • Publisher ‏ : ‎ Yale University Press; 1st edition (April 8, 2008)
  • Language ‏ : ‎ English
  • Hardcover ‏ : ‎ 293 pages
  • ISBN-10 ‏ : ‎ 9780300122237
  • ISBN-13 ‏ : ‎ 978-0300122237
  • Item Weight ‏ : ‎ 1.35 pounds
  • Dimensions ‏ : ‎ 9.4 x 6.5 x 1.2 inches
  • Customer Reviews:
    4.5 4.5 out of 5 stars 1,818 ratings

About the authors

Follow authors to get new release updates, plus improved recommendations.

Customer reviews

4.5 out of 5 stars
4.5 out of 5
1,818 global ratings

Top reviews from the United States

Reviewed in the United States on October 23, 2008
This is a terrific book. The authors cover terrain which has been explored recently in books such as "Predictably Irrational" and "Sway" -- loosely speaking, why we humans persistently engage in behavior patterns which do not benefit us in the long term. Their own research, at the University of Chicago, builds upon the work of Tversky and Kahneman in behavioral economics; the behavioral insights gained form the basis for public policy changes in a number of different areas.

The book provides a funny, engaging, remarkably clear exposition of the various factors which lead us to make poor decisions. This alone would make it worth reading. What makes it exceptional is that they actually suggest *remedies* that might help us save ourselves from our own flawed gut instincts. Indeed, they go one step further, making a convincing argument for incorporating these remedies as a part of public policy. The examples that they consider are directly relevant to decisions each of us faces routinely: choices that primarily affect our own welfare, like decisions about health and lifestyle, credit and money management, investing for retirement; and choices with broader societal implications, like those pertaining to environmental behavior, organ donation, charitable giving and community involvement. They use the term "libertarian paternalism" to characterize their public policy recommendations; don't allow the term to put you off - their suggestions really make a lot of sense.

"Nudge" is very well-written and extremely readable. I was impressed by the amount of useful and interesting material the authors managed to incorporate in just 250 pages. I highly recommend this book.
5 people found this helpful
Report
Reviewed in the United States on April 19, 2008
Cognitive bias presents a real challenge to political philosophy - a challenge that has not yet been seriously dealt with by anyone. Economics has wrestled seriously over the question of whether people are "rational," and some would count "behavioral" economics as a criticism of neoclassical economics. Less fruitfully, critical theory has fumbled around with the literature of bias, citing it as yet another reason that "it's all subjective."

But nobody has looked seriously at what a legal regime that systematically corrected for bias would look like. The notion of epistemological "planning" scares me to death. But in this easily-readable masterwork Sunstein and Thaler take a different, more modest, tack. They assume that individuals seeking to accomplish common goals will inevitably organize themselves into institutions (families, firms, governments - doesn't matter) and that cognitive psychology can sometimes predict how humans will react to them. This means that bureaucrats (or, for that matter, advertisers) may succesfully shape our behavior by chosing certain organizational forms (the placement of sugary cereal near the floor of the supermarket). The authors' crucial insight is that we, too, can shape our own behavior through legislation. And in this way, they argue, we can make ourselves more free.

It will be objected (by me for instance) that "we" (the group) have no right to conduct this sort of liberation on the individual. The authors anticipate this objection with the additional proviso of "no coercion." This is not unlike Randy Barnett's argument that, since rule by consent is a myth, the only legitimate governmental actions are those to which no one could possibly object (see 
Restoring the Lost Constitution: The Presumption of Liberty ). On Thaler and Sunstein's account, government may legitimately correct for the cognitive bias of individual citizens, so long as the citizen can, upon reflection, opt out and do the "irrational" thing anyway. They recognize that, for their argument to hold together, the cost of exercising personal choice must be zero. But they point out that this is frequently the case, since most social institutions require default rules anyway. One must choose whether to save or spend a dollar - a default rule that allocates your paycheck to your bank account is no more "costly" in principle than one which places the money in your hand. The check must be cashed either way, but the saving rule may better serve your rational self-interest.

Where it is limited to these sorts of "no cost/no coercion" maneuvers, this kind of social engineering is extremely difficult to object to on moral grounds. After all, when we are rational or willfully irrational, this "libertarian paternalism" is no paternalism at all. But this book is haunted by the specter of passive irrationality. Not all nudges are benign. The authors are mapping (if not paving) the road to the most subtle and effective totalitarianism in history. Indeed, it may already be here.
14 people found this helpful
Report
Reviewed in the United States on December 25, 2008
REALLY BEHAVIORAL BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
By Paul Brandon
Emeritus Professor of Psychology
Minnesota State University, Mankato

The term BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS is used to refer to two very different disciplines. Most commonly, the term refers to an extension of cognitive psychology to economic phenomena; Nudge, by Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein, is an example of this application. However, the term can also be applied to the application of the principles of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior (Radical or Skinnerian Behaviorism) to these phenomena. I will show how Nudge's explanations can be re-analyzed from this perspective.
The graph below is an early example of applying EAB methods to the study of classic economic concepts; in this case a rat working for various reinforcers at various fixed ratio requirements in an operant conditioning chamber. As one would expect, the demand elasticity for saccharin solutions was greater than that for plain water, or for ethanol solutions.
SOME ISSUES TO WATCH FOR:
Parsimony.
Does an explanatory system introduce unnecessary constructs that don't add predictive power or an ability to control the subject matter?
Scalability and Sustainability.
These are two separate issues -- both are important.
Will a principle demonstrated on a small scale (lab, pilot study) be as effective on a more significant scale?
Will an immediate change in behavior produced by some operation be maintained over the long run without planning for maintenance conditions?

`Nudge' appears to be mainstream behavioral economics; economists attempting to make their analysis more realistic by replacing the completely rational Economic Man of classical economic analysis with a more realistic version derived from the decision theoretical work of Tversky and Kahneman. Nothing theoretically radical here. In fact, its roots can be traced back to John B. Watson (yes, that Watson), the founder of advertising psychology and behaviorism. Nudge is an example of Cognitive Behavioral Economics: derived from cognitive psychology principles.
Thaler and Sunstein spend a lot of time talking about the Automatic and Reflective selves; little homunculi residing in the mind and controlling behavior. Talking about verbal and direct contingency governance as a function of history and current contingencies is much more effective. Their distinction maps well onto the distinction between verbally governed behavior and behavior under direct contingency control (see below).
Ultimately their work is very empirical. Their cognitizing gives the appearance of an explanation without adding power in terms of control and prediction.
The authors' point is that classical economics is in fact a poor guide to action if we want to be effect in changing what people do. Instead they propose some empirically supported strategies for behavior change which they derive from some recent work in the area of decision theory, although (as I will point out) many of the strategies they propose can be more parsimoniously derived from other conceptual systems.
In fact, this is a good example of parallel evolution.
Thaler and Sunstein are responding to the same environmental situations as behaviorists do, and it is not surprising that the common set of contingencies (observed patterns of human behavior) occasion similar verbal behavior. What has surprised me as I read the book is that my typical response is not `how dumb', but `of course.' They suggest generally the same courses of action that I would as a behaviorist; I (and more so behavioral behavioral economists such as Steven Hursh, Timothy Hackenberg and Greg Madden) might suggest some detail differences, but by and large what they suggest makes good behavioral sense.
One of the strengths of the book's approach to human behavior is the acknowledgment that we make choices for a reason -- and that these reasons can often be identified. There is no such thing as purely autonomous choice independent of outside influences. Therefore, our choice is not between influence and lack of influence, but whether we will study and use these influences to better our lives. Ignorance is not bliss, nor is it healthy.
Thaler and Sunstein sugar coat this by using the label `libertarian paternalism', but underlying their argument is the assumption that behavior is not ultimately autonomous, and that the job of `choice architects' (those who manage behavior in any sense) is to identify the aspects of the environment that control actions of interest, and to change behavior by changing the relevant aspects of the environment.
The book follows a basic pattern:
The authors first describe how a rational and knowledgeable Economic Person (an Econ) would approach some decision situation, then document how real people (Humans) actually behave, and finally describe some way of restructuring the situation (a Nudge) that would cause Humans to behave in a way more to their long term benefit.

Some examples of the behavioral processes involved:
Contingency traps
One behavioral concept that they appear to be developing is that of the contingency trap.
This is the observation that immediate consequences (reinforcers) are more effective than delayed ones. Many human problems are due to the fact that a given action usually has more than one consequence. If the immediate consequence is reinforcing, but the long term outcome is harmful, we have a contingency trap. Health risks like overeating and smoking fit into this category. Again, the problem is how to rearrange the environment (particularly the social environment) to provide prompts for behaviors with delayed positive outcomes rather than immediate ones.
Rule governed behavior
On of the ways out of a contingency trap is to bring behavior under the control of verbal rules.
Often this works by making contingencies more obvious.
In the Nudge context, this is described by terms such as consumer education, getting people to forgo immediate reinforcers that have more delayed and diffuse long-term effects. They apply this to a free market (cap-and-trade) approach to pollution, to overcome the political difficulties involved in getting legislation enacted.
Social Influence
Not surprisingly, the authors devote a chapter to this topic; again it's pretty straightforward.
In behavioral terms (not theirs) social influence can be divided into two categories: modeling (doing what one sees others doing, and getting reinforced for doing) and social reinforcement (direct peer pressure; approval or disapproval of one's actions). An additional process is referred to as `priming': prompting an initial step in the sequence of actions necessary to achieve a goal.
Despite their `libertarian' stance, they don't seem to find peer pressure unacceptable as a way to change behavior, although their preference is for various forms of prompting.
Response cost
Thaler and Sunstein have discovered that the cost of doing something affects the likelihood of taking action.
In particular, people tend to follow the Law of Least Effort (this concept goes back to Thorndike). Among other things, this results in behavioral `inertia' since doing nothing (no change) requires less effort than doing something (such as changing one's asset allocations)
Thus, in discussing `opt-in' vs `opt-out' methods of having people enroll in programs such as retirement savings, they recommend structuring the programs so that the default action is enrolling in a program, with a positive action required to opt out of it. The same analysis is applied to the task of increasing organ donations.
Another point: the default payment options on credit cards are a minimum payment that maximizes the company's interest income. Their alternative: make it an equal effort forced choice between minimum payment and complete balance payment.

Delay Discounting:
The tendency for organisms to assign a greater value to immediate consequences than to delayed ones. This is often coupled with risk aversiveness: the observation that organisms assign higher values to losses and aversive events that to gains and positive ones.
A note: In experimental work on matching, immediate and delayed consequences are usually both certain.
In the real world, increased delay is usually correlated with increased uncertainty.
It is reasonable to suspect that discounting could be acquired through either natural selection or through experience.
Populations in more uncertain environments should show more discounting (greater k). This is also consistent with the matching law, since delayed outcomes would be associated with less frequent reinforcement.

########################

As I've indicated, there is another field of behavioral economics.
This is a group of behavior analysts (Skinnerian or Radical Behaviorism) who have incorporated some of the concepts of economics such as value delay discounting and demand elasticity into the terms of behavior analysis, and can be looked at as an application of proven behavioral principles. Specifically, we avoid what is in their terms coercion by emphasizing existing stimulus control rather than programmed reinforcement or punishment. Thaler and Sunstein's distinction between Automatic and Reflective Systems maps easily onto the behavioral distinction between contingency and rule governed behavior: behavior governed by direct contact with outcomes versus behavior controlled by learned verbal rules.
Basic assumption of the book: people have response biases that can harm them unless `we' pre-empt them by using `biases' (common behavioral predispositions) positively.
Behavioral Economics of either variety raises interesting questions about behavior and consequences on any but the broadest molar level. When one signs up for a savings plan. what is the behavior, and what consequences control it. This sort of situation is almost always multiply determined.

########################

WHAT IS `NUDGE'?
How to make it easy for people to do what they really `want' to do.
`Libertarian Paternalism' is reminiscent of `kinder and gentler'; trying to have it both ways; control and freedom.
Libertarianism is very much in line with Skinner's preference for positive reinforcement and relatively subtle contingencies vs. obvious and aversive control. Thaler and Sunstein say that control is OK if there is a choice in the sense of the physical possibility of doing something else.
Much of it describes what we would term a set of prompts to make individual and socially beneficial behaviors more likely. The authors also describe ways in which we can rearrange reinforcement contingencies to take advantage of phenomena such as delay discounting to minimize the immediate cost of making a commitment to behaviors such as investing which have immediate costs and long term benefits.

###########

Nudge overall strategy:
1. Structuring the environment to make effective discrimination (choice under stimulus control) easy and accurate.
Limit the number of choices. Makes discriminative stimuli as simple as possible.

2. Design contingencies (economic systems) to make it likely that people make `good' choices (self beneficial).
`Nudge' by manipulating stimuli and response costs.

########################

EXAMPLES
A good example of the way in which they apply these principles is the Save More Tomorrow program developed by Thaler and Schlomo Benartzi.
This program is based on the principle of making a verbal commitment now (a behavior with a low response cost) to do something in the future which has a high response cost. This is very similar to Hayes' ACT (Acceptance and Commitment Therapy).
In this case, they start with a standard savings plan where people sign up for an automatic periodic transfer of funds to a savings account.
The added detail is a commitment to a gradual increase in the size of the deduction (some echos of progressive ratio reinforcement schedules here), thus reducing the aversiveness of a large initial payment.
They also talk about `inertia' as a factor both in maintaining behavior and resisting change; reminiscent of Tony Nevin's Behavioral Momentum Theory, which might provide some additional suggestions for developing this program.
Finally, gradually increasing payments reminiscent of progressive ratio schedules.
A lot of use of immediate commitments (often verbal behaviors) with low response costs with a larger delayed cost. An example of a commitment would be agreeing to present this paper. The immediate response cost is very low, while the work requirement over the next several months was considerable.
A lot of legislation fits this pattern (see Health Care).
An example of a situation calling for a Nudge is FaceBook security.
Facebook's security settings were recently upgraded, but require several stages of box clicking (have YOU done it?). A better arrangement would be a single default checkbox for maximum security settings, leaving the detailed (and time consuming option) for decreased security tradeoffs.

########################

PROBLEMS AND ISSUES
There is too much reliance on rules not backed up by consequences.
While making a big deal of the difference between Humans and Econs, they seem to assume that simply providing information about costs and benefits of behavior will be enough to change people's choices.
A good example of this is their analysis of medical malpractice lawsuits. They seem to feel that people might trade off their right to sue in exchange for lower medical fees. This seems to assume that Humans are Econs and make rational choices based on economic considerations.
An alternative might be the well known psychological principle of minimizing the maximum loss (a mini-max strategy). People will trade off the lowest long-term cost in exchange for minimizing that maximum possible loss. That is why few people will choose to self insure, even if that results in the lowest predicted long term cost.
Lack of good data.
Reliance on media reports, personal communications and observations, Web sites and books rather that published articles and official statistics. Anecdotal rather than systematic support.
It is not clear that their Nudges are as effective as they say that they are.
Sustainability: very little mention (if any!) of long term followup.
Typically info of the sort `the bank said that savings rates increased by 40%'.
Thaler and Sunstein talk a lot (at least implicitly) about how organizations can Nudge individuals. How do Individuals Nudge organizations. They DO admit that their emphasis is on government. Thaler and Sunstein are probably better suited than behaviorists are (they have put in years of government and corporate work) to get their insights applied, although the field of Organization Behavior Management has some chops in this area.
Thaler and Sunstein do not seem to be concerned with coercion, except to state that as long as the possibility of choice exists (more than one possible behavior in a situations) coercion does NOT exist.
Example: They do not (seem to) understand why people object to an open market for organ donation, or to mandatory organ donation systems. Commoditizing organs invokes contingencies that could coerce people to make risky exchanges of organs for money.
They talk a lot about invoking `social influence' but do not do the kind of explicit analysis that would distinguish between discriminative and reinforcing functions. For instance, they talk about using advertising to `Nudge' people to change (discriminative) but do not consider the (also social) reinforcement contingencies necessary to make advertising effective.
The magic of the Nudge!
Relying on the `Hand of the Market' and transparency may be good Libertarianism, but it is weak counter control. Who watches the watchers? Controls the controllers? From a contingency analysis point of view, the hand follows the money; the more immediate the payoff (quarterly reports) the better.
Transparency is good, but there is not reason to suppose that by itself it will lead to effective counter control.
To the extent that Nudgers are public or private sector bureaucrats they are insulated from counter control, since they are interchangeable (you never know who you will speak to when you call an airline, so the contingencies linking your behavior and theirs are very diffuse). The authors themselves are actively engaged in Nudging. They deal with existing contingencies and make a case for their benevolence.
Beyond transparency (their main solution) is there an easy (or even practical) way to implement the sort of counter control manager contingency that B. F. Skinner did in Walden II? Again, the question of Scalability!
Their final Nudge involves the mortgage crisis.
Their solution is their RECAP procedure -- making terms easier to understand.
This doesn't change the low immediate response cost of low teaser rates and minimal down payments.
The real answer is to change the contingencies by barring initial low rates unless they are combined with points so that an initial response cost is required (go back to limiting percentage covered to 85% of value.)
The RECAP procedure involve lengthy (often private) verbal chains; a response cost that must be offset by immediate reinforcement.

########################

THE BEHAVIORAL RESPONSE
In general, the book's analysis is very consistent with the predictions and recommendations that a behavior analyst would make, to the point where I wonder if the ghost of Israel Goldiamond is still roaming the halls of the University of Chicago where the authors are affiliated.
Much of their analysis can be put into a structure of concurrent chains.
They identify two (occasionally more) alternative behavioral sequences involved in some choice situations (such as whether or not to pollute), and then discuss ways in which the contingencies of the competing chains might be altered. This could be as simple as changing the controlling stimuli to make the desired behavior more likely, or if necessary to decrease its response cost, or as a last resort, to more directly modify the consequences in terms of reinforcing or punishing outcomes.
The fact that a chain is always involved; people always have a choice in the sense of available alternative behaviors, allows them to maintain their `paternalistic libertarian' stance. Thus, they support the use of cap-and-trade systems as an approach to pollution control since it would embed some positive reinforcement contingencies which would result in a decrease in the choice of polluting industrial practices, rather than simply mandating a target (they use the phrase "command-and-control") for pollution reduction.
This sort of distinction is sometimes more apparent than real; a choice between two possible behaviors is present in both cap-and-trade and direct regulation.
In the one case, the choice is between paying a tax for polluting on the one hand, and not polluting on the other.
In the case of direct regulation, the choice is between polluting and suffering some penalty for violating the regulation, versus not polluting.
Thus, the difference between the two situations is the nature of the contingencies, not the presence or absence of choice.
Another behavior principle that might bear attention is 'response adduction': the tendency for an increase in behavior maintained by one reinforcement system to produced an increase in the frequency of other related reinforcement systems.
As a related point, they talk about the problems involved with too many choices (Barry Schwartz has written on this, although they don't cite him). Medicare D plans are a good example: it's almost impossible to make a good choice given the number and complexity of alternatives.
Verbal Behavior is a class of behavior with its own contingencies; not a `window on the mind' (underlying mental processes). Recognizing verbal behavior as an act in its own right clears up a lot of the `inconsistencies' between what people say they should do and what they actually do (different consequences).
The behavior answer to control is not `free will' or `free choice'; it's counter control. Nudge is all control. They seem to be saying that Econs are controlled primarily by economic outcomes; Humans by Nudges and incentives. We know about the four term contingency (context, situation, behavior, consequence) -- it's the type of contingency that differs. Nudges must be backed up to be effective.
Finally, the whole idea of `libertarianism' (paternalistic, maternalistic, or otherwise) seems to contradict the deterministic assumptions of behaviorism. From the point of view of the behaviorist, freedom is just another word (see Baum's text for a good analysis of the uses of the term). People do not behave freely in the sense of being autonomous actors, but rather their behavior is determined by the interaction between genetics, experience, and consequences. Our goal is not to maximize freedom (except in the limited sense of absence of aversive control), but rather to promote the use of contingencies which will maximize human welfare.
The maintenance of behavior, not just its acquisition, is a behavioral priority (charter schools are an example of the perils of ignoring this issue).
They mention lot of standard behavioral self control techniques, such as ceding reinforcer control to another individual, without acknowledging the original sources. In general, self control can be analyzed as taking an action which changes contingencies in a way that in turn changes your behavior.
For example: put the cookies on a shelf that requires the use of a step ladder to get at them (increased response cost).
Whenever possible, shorten behavior chains (they say `one click') required for desired behavior.
Walden II may have been the original statement of behavioral economics in the sense that economics is the structure of a culture as it accomplishes tasks. Skinner's `managers' sound a lot like Thaler and Sunstein's `Choice Architects'. Skinner incorporated more explicit counter control, though.
Kristof (NYT, 5/23/2010) writes that in some third world countries poor people spend more money on alcohol than on their children's education (supposedly 'free' schools often charge a fee). This is predictable from delay discounting and matching,
What sort of 'nudge' would help? Social pressure and/'or advertising as suggested by the authors? Behavior analysis suggests a more direct contingency modification of the sort that Thaler and Sunstein dislike.
Put a tax on alcohol (levied on bars) and use the proceeds to fund education, making the fees unnecessary. The increase in cost would also reduce drinking somewhat (although demand elasticity must be considered). Thaler and Sunstein would say that this is bad because a tax eliminates free choice. From a behavioral perspective it simply substitutes are more obvious form of behavioral control, and in fact a tax on consumption always leaves the option of not consuming.
Some other behavioral applications:
Drug abuse: voucher programs. Consequence allocation of the sort not considered in Nudge.
Behavior/consequence relationships.
Token economies (Hackenberg)
Some factual issues as stated by the authors:
Disulfram (Antabuse) is not in fact very effective when people can exit the system.
Subliminal advertising is not effective (actually; only small changes can be made in already existing response probabilities. Can't turn NO into YES).
NYC experience with posting nutritional information in restaurants is disappointing.
School vouchers don't work (Cleveland and Milwaukee proved that when they randomly gave vouchers only to some applicants because availability was limited).
Social Security was never intended to be a savings program.

########################

My final question is, therefore, do we as Behavior Analysts have a unique contribution to make in the sense of suggesting solutions that are basically and profoundly different from those suggested by non-behaviorists, are do we (at least in the case of social engineering) tend to converge on the same basic solutions?
In the latter case, our contribution would not be in the uniqueness of our analysis but in the efficiency of its implementation. As I have tried to demonstrate, a non-behavioral analysis based on some nonsystematic decision principles and some canny observations can be more parsimoniously analyzed in behavioral terms. In addition, we might avoid the consequences of pursuing some of the false distinctions implicit in the concept of libertarianism. This, in turn, should lead to a more effective implementation.
13 people found this helpful
Report

Top reviews from other countries

Translate all reviews to English
Francesco Negro
5.0 out of 5 stars fantastic
Reviewed in Italy on January 21, 2021
Eye-opening, I would strongly recommend this reading, together with the classical Kahnemann, to all high school students to prepare them for life
Nelson Senra
5.0 out of 5 stars Professor e Pesquisador
Reviewed in Brazil on July 10, 2019
Excelente conteúdo. Quem se interessa por economia irá se interessar fortemente por esse livro. A economia comportamental é apresentada e exemplificada com maestria.
Ricardo
5.0 out of 5 stars Muy buen libro
Reviewed in Mexico on March 8, 2018
Muy buen libro, tal como se muestra en la descripción del mismo
M u y r e c o m e n d a b l e
One person found this helpful
Report
T. O'Reilly
5.0 out of 5 stars Fascinating.
Reviewed in Canada on December 14, 2017
An absolutely fascinating book that examines a powerful aspect of influencing human behaviour.
One person found this helpful
Report
Samuel Borralho
5.0 out of 5 stars Fast pace delivering and item as ordered
Reviewed in Spain on October 11, 2018
Fast pace delivering and item as ordered